A Bettor World
From the May/June 2007 Issue
Filed under: Big
Ideas, Economic
Policy, Public
Square
Once apprenticed to a bookie, Justin
Wolfers of Wharton now draws economic insight from the behavior of gamblers.
Sitting
in front of a roaring fire in his Philadelphia townhouse, an Australian-born
economist named Justin Wolfers puts his feet up on an ottoman, revealing a
pair of pink and black wingtips. His living room is filled with white leather
furniture, the dining room sports an Italian glass table surrounded by
orange chairs, and the kitchen could be a stage set from the Food Network.He takes a sip of red wine and asks his guest, “Would you bet me five dollars I’m wearing red underwear? No, you wouldn’t. Why not? Because you know I have better information than you do.” His point is that smart people with good information are attracted to markets by the existence of ignorant bettors. Wolfers knows the concept well: in college, he worked as a runner for a Sydney bookmaker. An assistant professor of business and public policy at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, Wolfers, age 34, is fascinated by what are called prediction markets. The behavior of people who place bets at a track, with their own money at stake, has always been a great predictor of the outcome of races. Today, the concept is being applied in more serious contexts. Last year, for instance, the aggregate of small bettors who placed wagers on electoral results on TradeSports, a Web-based market, forecasted the outcome of every U.S. Senate race correctly. Companies like Best Buy, the electronics retailer, now maintain in-house markets where employees bet on how products will sell. The results help with pricing and inventory decisions. Wolfers says that companies have shifted to prediction markets because they work better than the traditional means for gathering data and making forecasts, such as sales meetings. “Think of what a meeting is,” Wolfers says. “It’s some fat, obnoxious guy who talks for three minutes despite the fact that he knows nothing. In the meantime, there’s a woman who sits in the back and says nothing because she may feel her opinion isn’t taken into account. And then there’s the brown-noser, who wants to be senior VP and will say anything the boss wants to hear.” When you set up a prediction market in which employees bet actual cash, you weed out those who don’t know anything. As for the sycophant: if the boss isn’t watching, he’s more likely to bet what he really thinks. With a prediction market, everyone brings a small piece of information to the table, and the consensus proves surprisingly accurate. Prediction markets aren’t this young economist’s only interest. Wolfers is what some call a forensic researcher, who sifts through data to test popularly held beliefs. He investigated voting behavior and confirmed that the electorate rewards—or punishes—state governors for economic trends beyond their control. He used the flow of news on election day last year to find that a rise in the probability of a Republican victory was causing (rather than following from) an uptick in equity prices. He even used a blind taste test to confirm that his current wine glasses make the wine taste better. One of his most controversial findings is that the death penalty does not save lives by discouraging potential murderers. In 1976, the U.S. Supreme Court overturned a national prohibition on capital punishment, citing studies that concluded that capital punishment does indeed deter crime. But those findings, Wolfers and his colleague John Donohue found, depended on faulty statistical assumptions.
Economist
Wolfers is fascinated by the power of 'prediction markets,' which use the
dynamic of gambling to make remarkably accurate forecasts on everything from
elections to new-product revenues.
“The fundamental
difficulty,” they wrote, “is that the death penalty—at least as it has been
implemented in the United States—is applied so rarely that the number of
homicides that it can plausibly have caused or deterred cannot be reliably
disentangled from the large year-to-year changes in the homicide rate caused
by other factors.” Their conclusion, in an article in the Stanford Law
Review, was that there is “not just reasonable doubt about whether there is
any deterrent effect of the death penalty, but profound uncertainty.”
Says Wolfers:
“The Supreme Court decision cited academic research that was wrong. At the
very least, you want these guys to debate the issue with facts that are
true.”
Wolfers earned
his bachelor’s in economics at the University of Sydney with first-class
honors in 1994, then went to work at the Reserve Bank of Australia, the
country’s central bank. In 1997, he arrived at Harvard for Ph.D. work,
planning to return home with his sights on becoming Secretary to the Treasury
some day. Unlike his father, a political science professor, he preferred
public policy to academe.
But after just a
few months at Harvard, one of his advisers invited Wolfers to a meeting of
the National Bureau of Economic Research, the prestigious organization
headed by Martin Feldstein, who chaired President Reagan’s Council of
Economic Advisers. The room was filled with some of the best economists in
the world, conducting exciting, original research. Wolfers decided then on
the academic life in the United States. He would not be returning to
Australia.
“I realized that
what was happening in that room—50 central banks from around the world were
more or less going to take those ideas and implement them. I thought, wow!
This is a lot more exciting than being the guy back home who replicates
their research,” Wolfers said.
Marriage and
divorce are recurring research topics for Wolfers, whose own parents
divorced when he was 14. He sees widespread misconceptions. Americans often
compare today with the 1950s to highlight the deterioration of family life.
But he found that the 1950s were anomalous—a time of exceptionally high
family stability by historical standards. Also, contrary to what is commonly
believed, men are not getting married later in life. Most men still marry in
their early twenties, about the same age men wed 100 years ago. The
significant difference today, he says, is that the age gap between a man and
his wife has narrowed.
Wolfers and his
domestic partner, Betsey Stevenson, who is also an assistant professor in
the same department at Wharton, studied 150 years of marriage and divorce
data and concluded that, contrary to popular belief, more lenient laws have
not led to a significant long-term increase in divorce. Instead, rates spiked
when divorce became easier, then retreated toward their earlier levels.
Meanwhile, the two concluded in an article last year in The Quarterly Journal
of Economics that the liberalization of divorce laws coincided with sharp
declines in rates of domestic violence, as well as declines in suicide rates
among married women—though not married men.
The
best-known research that Wolfers has conducted involves cheating by
basketball players. Because teams are often unevenly matched, with easily
predictable winners and losers, bookmakers offer bets on whether the
difference in a score will exceed a certain number of points, called the
“spread.” Establishing a spread is an attempt to divide gamblers evenly in
their guesses. One hazard of this approach is that players on a team that is
heavily favored, especially in basketball, can bet against themselves, then
try to fail at beating the spread (by missing easy shots or letting the other
team score) while still winning the game. This practice is known as “point
shaving.”
In The American
Economic Review last year, Wolfers examined 40,000 National Collegiate
Athletic Association basketball games from the last 16 years and found
striking results: When a team was favored by 12 points or fewer, the winner
beat the spread about 50 percent of the time, as one would expect. But in
games in which teams were favored by more than 12 points, the winning team
covered the spread only 47 percent of the time—an indication that something
other than chance was at play. Wolfers concluded that point shaving appears
to occur in about 5 percent of the games in which there is a heavy favorite.
The finding caused an uproar in the sports world.
“He’s very
creative, in terms of asking interesting research questions,” says Eric Zitzewitz,
a highly regarded assistant professor of economics at Stanford’s business
school who has known Wolfers for years and collaborated with him on such
projects as a chapter on prediction markets in the book, Information Markets: A New Way of Making Decisions, published
by AEI-Brookings Press.
Zitzewitz says
it was Wolfers’s idea to use an online prediction market to assess the
economic impact of the war in Iraq, before the U.S. invaded. Up to that
point, academics had only used prediction markets for retrospective insight
into historical events. But in the Iraq study, which Zitzewitz and Wolfers
wrote with Australian economist Andrew Leigh, the authors used markets to
evaluate the cost of a policy before it was instituted—an approach that
suggests such markets could be used to guide policy. They noted that prices
of oil on futures markets implied a belief that an oil price spike caused by
war would dissipate after about 18 months, limiting the size of an “oil
dividend.” This prediction, as it happens, has not been borne out by
events—oil is still well above its pre-war prices. But analysts believe that
today’s prices may be due to other factors that were not considered before
the Iraq war, including the disruptions caused by Hurricane Katrina.
While Wolfers’s
study was inconclusive, Zitzewitz said that “it was a really creative way of
approaching the policy-relevant question, ‘Should we go to war?’ Justin is
technically competent, and he’s well trained, but he’s not
super-mathematical. He doesn’t delve into new econometric techniques. He
simply takes existing techniques and applies them to really interesting
questions.”
Not every
economist is so enthusiastic. Paul Rubin, who wrote one of the death penalty
studies that Wolfers attacked, criticizes him for publishing the article in a
student-edited law journal rather than an economic journal, where his paper
would have been subjected to more rigorous scrutiny. In addition, Rubin says,
when the study was concluded, Wolfers gave him only three days to comment on
what was a lengthy, detailed econometric critique.
Wolfers is
undeterred. After all, the death penalty research was also published as a
working paper by the National Bureau of Economic Research, where he has been
a research fellow for the past four years. And he continues to apply economic
principles to interesting social issues. He’s currently studying whether NBA
referees racially discriminate, looking at whether the number of fouls
earned by black and white players varies with the race of the referee. He
also continues to research whether there are alternative methods for
forecasting election outcomes. And he and Stevenson are looking more deeply
at what has caused the dramatic changes in the American family over the last
century.
He likes the
life he’s chosen. “I could do the same work I’m doing now for an Australian
institution, and the truth is, no one would listen,” he says. But from his
perch at Wharton, his work finds its way to financiers, business leaders, and
policymakers all over the world.
Caren Chesler
is a writer based in New York.
|
No comments:
Post a Comment